VOLUME 22 SEPTEMBER 2006 353–368
DOI:10.1093/esr/jcl001, available onliOnline publication 28 April 2006
Social Networks and Labour Market Outcomes: The Non-Monetary Benefits of Social Capital
We contrast Granovetter’s hypothesis (Granovetter, M. (1973). American Journal of Sociol- ogy, 78, 1360–1380; Granovetter, M. (1974). Getting a Job: A Study of Contacts and Careers. University of Chicago Press; Granovetter, M. (1995). Getting a Job: A Study of Con- tacts and Careers. University of Chicago Press) that social networks help individuals to find better-paid jobs with a new model, which predicts that networks are helpful with respect to non-pecuniary job characteristics but not concerning the monetary pay-offs. Following Montgomery (Montgomery, J. D. (1992) American Sociological Review, 57, 586–596), our model is a combination of classical job-search theory and the network hypothesis. First, concerning the monetary consequences, we test our hypotheses empirically by analysing the 2001 International Social Survey Programme on social relations and support systems. We show that using social ties is a common job-search strategy in all countries. However, using social networks does not increase the monetary pay-off. Second, we use a sample of 8,000 Swiss university graduates who recently entered the labour market to show that informal job-search channels are beneficial with respect to important non-monetary job characteristics. Thus, graduates who received their jobs through social contacts tended to get jobs that are linked to their educational degree and offer better career perspectives. Furthermore, using personal networks is related to lower search costs. Therefore, the results suggest overall that networks improve the non-pecuniary characteristics but not the monetary pay-offs. Introduction
First, he proposed that many employees find their jobsthrough social contacts and not only through formal
Since Granovetter’s (1974) Getting a Job, the question of
channels such as direct applications, employment
how individuals find jobs and what effect social contacts
agencies, or job advertisements. Second, according to
have on the labour market has emerged to be one of the
Granovetter, the use of social networks allows job seek-
most interesting and controversial research questions in
ers to gather better information about the availability
labour market research. Granovetter’s (1973, 1974)
of jobs as well as job characteristics. This informational
central ideas can be summarized as three hypotheses.
advantage should enable job seekers to select better
The Author 2006. Published by Oxford University Press. All rights reserved. For permissions, please e-mail: journal
FRANZEN AND HANGARTNER
jobs. Hence a job found through the network should
Are Granovetter’s Hypotheses
result in a better match, that is, higher wages and
Refuted?
higher job satisfaction. Third, information about thelabour market can best be generated through weak ties.
Granovetter’s (1974) original study is based on a sam-
The advantage of weak ties as opposed to strong ties
ple of 282 professionals, technical, and managerial
lies in the fact that the information in close-friendship
workers1 living in Newton, Massachusetts, who were
circles is rather redundant and similar and that more
interviewed by him and partly surveyed by written
new information is generated by networks whose
questionnaires in 1969. Fifty-six per cent reported that
members are dispersed and dissimilar.
they found their jobs through social contacts. This res-
Granovetter’s first proposition has been confirmed in
ult has been reconfirmed repeatedly in many studies in
many studies. Most empirical research shows that a sub-
the United States (U.S. Department of Labor, 1975;
stantial proportion of individuals find their jobs via their
Corcoran et al., 1980; Marsden and Campbell, 1990;
contacts with friends, relatives, colleagues, or acquaint-
Staiger, 1990) as well as in Great Britain, Japan, and
ances. However, hypotheses two and three are contro-
The Netherlands (see Afterword in Granovetter, 1995).
versial. Extensive reviews by Granovetter (1995) himself
Some differences between studies appear from the fact
as well as others (Lin, 1999) suggest that most empirical
that sometimes only active job seekers are taken into
studies were not able to confirm the wage bonus. This
account. However, there is evidence that social con-
conclusion is nurtured by recent results presented by
tacts also play an important part in those matches in
Mouw (2003) who concludes that contacts have no
which respondents received an offer from an employer
causal effect on labour market outcomes.
without prior search. These respondents are often
These results raise the question whether the social
excluded from the analyses, a procedure that results in
embeddedness of individuals has any consequences at all
some biases as Granovetter convincingly argues. Stud-
on labour market outcomes. We argue that they have
ies that also pay attention to the ‘non-seekers’ show
consequences and will present theoretical arguments as
that in about 80 per cent of these cases, a friend or rela-
well as empirical evidence, which support the notion
tive was involved. Hence, Granovetter’s proposal that
that contacts matter. Jobs found through social contacts
networks are involved in about half of all job matches
have non-monetary benefits, particularly a better match
between employees’ education and the job require-
Granovetter’s second and third hypotheses, that jobs
ments. Furthermore, social networks reduce the search
found through social contacts are better paid and more
satisfying for employees and that weak ties are better
The remainder of the article is organized into four
than strong ties, are very controversial. Granovetter
sections. Are Granovetter’s Hypotheses Refuted? starts
(1974) found that 54 per cent of those who found their
with a brief review of existing findings, namely that most
jobs through contacts reported to be very satisfied with
studies show that networks do not matter with respect to
their work compared to 30 per cent who found their
earnings. We then refer to job-search theory and to
work through formal methods. Similarly, a larger pro-
Montgomery (1992) in order to explain these non-
portion (ten percentage points) of the former is found in
findings. Moreover, we formulate an extension of his
the higher income group. However, these findings were
model and propose that job offers obtained through
only replicated by a few studies (Corcoran et al., 1980;
social networks are superior with respect to non-monetary
Staiger, 1990; Wegener 1991; Coverdill, 1994; Jann,
characteristics. The ISSP 2001 describes our first data
2003), while many others could not detect a wage differ-
source and the results obtained. We analyse the ISSP
ential (Lin et al., 1981; Bridges and Villemez, 1986;
2001 data and show that jobs found through social con-
Marsden and Hurlbert, 1988; Preisendörfer and Voss,
tacts are not superior with respect to payment. In The
1988; Lin, 1999; Mau and Kopischke, 2001). Some stud-
Swiss Graduate Survey, we refer to another data source, a
ies (De Graaf and Flap, 1988; Flap and Boxmann, 2001)
survey of university graduates who entered the labour
even find a negative wage effect for social contacts. Fur-
market in 2001 to show that search strategies are related
ther evidence against Granovetter’s hypothesis has also
to the non-monetary job characteristics. In particular,
been presented recently by Lin (1999), and Mouw (2003)
we evaluate the outcomes of different job-search strate-
who concludes ‘I believe the weight of anecdotal evidence
gies with respect to earnings, educational adequacy, and
und intuition suggests that being “well connected” is
search costs. Finally, the last section concludes and dis-
an advantage in the labor market (.). At the moment,
cusses our findings and shortcomings. SOCIAL NETWORKS AND LABOUR MARKET OUTCOMES
intuition und anecdote aside, we have little empirical
shows that the expected wage from weak-tie offers may
be, counter-intuitively, lower than the wage expected
However, this conclusion holds only with respect to
from strong-tie offers. We extend Montgomery’s argu-
the direct effect, that is, for wages of those jobs that were
ment by applying them to the difference between formal
offered with the help of the social network. The litera-
and informal search channels instead of the difference
ture on social resources (see Lin, 1999) also demon-
between weak and strong ties. First, we assume that most
strated that individuals in high job positions are found
individuals use both formal (direct applications, answer-
to have a large social network as well. Hence, the two
ing job advertisements, placing an advertisement, using
findings that on the one hand high levels of social capital
a labour office) and informal (social contacts) search
are correlated with high-income jobs, but that using the
channels. Second, we assume that the wage distributions
network on the other hand does not affect the wage level
of both channels are identical. Thus, at least in principle,
constitute a paradox. Mouw (2003) suspects that high
most available jobs can be found by various search chan-
job positions and size (and quality) of social networks
nels and are not exclusively restricted to one specific
are merely associated and that both depend on unob-
search method. Third, we assume that the offer rate of
served individual characteristics. Hence, he speaks of
informal channels is higher than the one from formal
spurious social capital. However, an alternative interpre-
search methods. This assumption basically follows
tation is given by Montgomery (1992) who offers an
Granovetter who asserts that information about new job
interesting combination of economic job-search theory
opportunities is particularly efficiently (fast) transported
and Granovetter’s network hypothesis.
through network ties as compared with formal search
The difficulty of choosing a job is that job offers do
modes. In order to receive a formal offer, a job seeker
not arrive simultaneously but sequentially in time (e. g.
first has to find a job advertisement and has to issue a
Lippman and McCall, 1976). Thus, a job seeker is con-
formal application. This procedure takes more effort
fronted with the following decision problem: either to
and is more costly than receiving the information from a
accept an offer and stop searching or to reject the offer
network tie and applying with the help of the tie. Thus,
and continue searching. Since searching is costly (direct
we assume that almost every person receives one or
costs and opportunity costs), a worker who maximizes
more offers through the social network channel and only
lifetime earnings will accept an offer of wage wR (or
fewer offers through the formal channel. The problem
higher) if this offer exceeds his value of leisure and if he
now is that most of the time the number and quality of
does not expect to find a higher wage offer that compen-
job offers are unobserved. Instead what researchers (and
sates for the continued search costs (see Mortensen,
we) observe is only the accepted job and the search
1986). wR is called the reservation wage. Obviously, the
channel through which it was found. Thus, it could be
higher an individual’s reservation wage the longer his or
the case that an individual who accepted an offer
her search time until he or she finds a wage offer that
received through the formal channel passed on other
matches the reservation wage. Moreover, the reservation
offers from the social network. Hence, we infer that a
wage depends (among other things) on the arrival rate of
seeker who accepted a formal offer had on average more
job offers. The more offers an individual expects the
offers to choose from and was therefore better able to
higher is his or her reservation wage and the higher the
select the best offer. Those who accepted an offer from
probability of finding a better-paid job. Following Mont-
the social network are on average likely to have had
gomery (1992), one way to interpret the effect of social
fewer offers to choose from, which results in a lower
capital on wages is via the reservation wage. Individuals
with larger networks (or alternatively a higher propor-
Wages are of course not the only characteristics of
tion of weak ties) may expect to receive more job offers,
jobs. This notion is well known and accepted by many
which increases the reservation wage. This indirect effect
researchers. Particularly, we assume that in addition to
of social networks on earnings is in line with empirical
wages, workers consider how well they fit into a job in
findings reported by Lin (1999) and Mouw (2003).2
terms of their interests and qualifications. One indicator
Networks not only can affect the reservation wage but
concerning the quality of the match is how well a
can also have direct implication via the job-search strat-
worker’s education and qualifications fit the require-
egies. This is Granovetter’s crucial hypothesis who does
ments of the job. Let us call this the educational ade-
not consider the indirect effect via reservation wages.
quacy (a) of a job. We propose that among the jobs
Montgomery (1992) interprets Granovetter in the way
offered that are above the reservation wage, workers
that weak ties elicit more job offers than strong ties and
choose the one that best meets their qualifications. FRANZEN AND HANGARTNER
While we assume that the wage distributions of the
However, they differ in educational adequacy in such
formal and the informal offer distributions are identical,
a way that workers who found their job through the net-
the job adequacy distributions of both search channels
work should have jobs that match their qualification
are not. Our fourth and new assumption is that the ade-
better. Note that our argument that jobs found through
quacy distribution of jobs offered through social net-
the network have higher adequacy but no wage advant-
works should be stochastically superior concerning the
age implies that adequacy and wages are not positively
first and third moment of the distribution (see Figure 1).
correlated (ceteris paribus, particularly human capital).
More specifically, jobs from the formal offer distribution
There is often a trade-off between initial wages when
might be right skewed with respect to adequacy, because
entering the labour market and adequacy. However, this
on average more jobs have low than high adequacy. How-
counter-intuitive argument is in line with human capital
ever, the offer distribution from the social network should
theory (Becker, 1964; see also Acemoglu and Pischke,
be skewed to the left side, since networks offer more ade-
1999). Thus, jobs that offer general on-the-job training
quate than inadequate jobs. The rationale behind this
should have relative low initial payment and steeper
proposition is that the network is rather well informed
earning profiles since employees have to compensate
about the job seekers’ interest and qualifications and
employers for their training. Hence, the degree of gen-
selects jobs with higher adequacy. Alternatively, it could
eral training and job adequacy should be positively cor-
be argued that networks are usually homogenous, which
related. As will be shown below, the first implication
might also result in more adequate job offers. Of course,
(the non-positive correlation between wages and ade-
information about the educational requirements of jobs is
quacy) can be tested with our data. However, we have no
usually also transferred via formal channels. However, it
data to test the second implication, that is, the positive
seems reasonable to assume that the information available
correlation between adequacy and general training.
through networks is more detailed and more specific thaninformation received through formal channels.
With respect to wages, jobs that are offered through
The ISSP 2001
the network should not be superior to the formal channel-offer distribution. When members of a network transmit
The ISSP 2001 was conducted on social relations and
information about jobs to a seeker, they are probably
support systems in 28 countries.3 Next to some socio-
not very well informed about the wage of the job nor do
demographic information (earnings, education, and
they know a worker’s reservation wage. Wages are often
work experience), the surveys contain questions about
the result of negotiations between employer and
the number of respondents’ friends and how they found
employee. However, the network is usually very well
their present jobs. Thus, participants were asked to
informed about the qualification and education of a
report the number of close friends at the work place and
worker, and it filters jobs in such a way that it offers
in their neighbourhood, and other close friends. Fur-
what it believes to be a good match. Hence, our expecta-
thermore, they were asked ‘Please indicate how you first
tion is that jobs do not differ in wages depending
found out about work at your present employer’. We
on whether they were found with the help of the net-
grouped the answers into strong ties if participants
named family members, other relatives, or close friendsas contacts. Answers were grouped into the categoryweak ties if respondents said acquaintance. Table 1 dis-plays the percentages of strong- and weak-network con-tacts as well as the number of valid cases for theparticipating nations of the ISSP 2001. Overall, we canobserve a substantial degree of variance. Proportions ofnetwork contacts are comparatively high in the southernEuropean countries (Italy, Hungary, and Cyprus) as wellin some developing countries such as the Philippinesand Brazil. Relatively low proportions are observable inthe Scandinavian countries. The United States, Japan,and Germany are in the middle. With few exceptions
Figure 1 Job offer distributions from networks and formal
(most eastern European countries) and contrary to
channels. Note: a refers to job adequacy.
expectation, the proportion of strong-tie contacts is
SOCIAL NETWORKS AND LABOUR MARKET OUTCOMES Table 1 Job placement via social networks Strong ties (%) Weak ties (%) N NA, not available. Data source: ISSP 2001, own calculations.
larger than that of weak-tie contacts. However, this
We had to drop both countries from our analysis so
might be partly due to our coding of other relatives into
that we end up with 15 remaining nations. The esti-
the strong-tie category. Nonetheless, the descriptive
mated coefficient for education in model 1 of Table 2
impression presented in Table 1 confirms Granovetter’s
tells us that every additional year in education is
notion that on average a substantial amount of jobs are
rewarded on average by 7.9 per cent ((exp(0.076)–1) × 100)
increase in hourly wages. Also, the other results, the pos-
Next we analyse whether network size and job place-
itive but concave effect for work experience, confirm the
ment via social contacts are related to wages. Such analy-
well-known results of the standard income regressions.
ses are presented in Table 2. The first model is a standard
Next, in model 2, we introduce the network indicators
Mincer income OLS-regression model controlling for
and two dummy variables if respondents found their
country-specific differences by country dummies. In
jobs through strong or weak ties as compared with
order to compare the hourly incomes, we transformed
formal methods (reference group). First, the more
the national wages into purchasing power parity (PPP)
friends respondents have at work and the more other
units. Since the transition from the original currencies
friends they report to have, the higher their hourly wage.
into PPP units can be done much more reliably for
Thus, these results are in line with the hypothesis of
OECD members, we restrict our analysis to these. Fur-
Montgomery (1992) that those with more contacts on
thermore, some countries (e.g. Austria, Norway) have
average expect more job offers, which raises their reserva-
missing data with respect to some central variables
tion wage and finally also their realized wage. Counter-
(income, education, or network indicators).
intuitive is the negative effect of the number of friends in
FRANZEN AND HANGARTNER Table 2 Extended Mincer-type wage regressions P-values in parentheses, computed with Huber–White-corrected standard errors. *Significant at 0.05; **significant at 0.01. ~Under control of country dummies. Models 1 and 2 are estimated by ordinary least squares, model 3 is estimated by maximum likelihood. In all three models, the following OECD countries are included: Australia, Canada, Czech Republic, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Great Britain, Hungary, Japan, New Zealand, Poland, Spain, Switzerland, and the United States.
the neighbourhood. However, more wealthy people
confirm former empirical findings (Mouw, 2003) that job
might live further apart from each other in suburban
placement through social contacts is not positively associ-
neighbourhoods, which may reduce their neighbourhood
ated with higher wages. Furthermore, our analysis of the
contacts. The data also confirm the second part of Mont-
data confirms a hypothesis by Montgomery (1992) that
gomery’s (1992) argument, namely that respondents who
the size of the social network is positively related to wages.
accepted a job offered via a strong tie have on average alower wage. This negative effect can also be observed forweak ties confirming our extension of Montgomery’s
The Swiss Graduate Survey
(1992) model. Thus, respondents who accepted an offerthrough the network (weak or strong) either had a lower
Our second data source is a survey of all Swiss university
search time or did not receive as many formal job offers.
graduates, which has been conducted biannually by the
Both causes lead to a lower number of total job offers,
Swiss statistical office since 1977. This data is collected from
which has the consequence of reducing the realized wage.
university graduates one year after graduation via written
Finally, model 3 in Table 2 is a multilevel model in which
questionnaires and is concerned with respondents’
the country dummies are replaced by country-specific
entrance (first job) into the labour market. We analyse the
covariates that should affect wages, such as GDP per cap-
newest available data of respondents who graduated in
ita, GDP growth, and the labour force participation of
2000.4 In this year, 12,447 graduates left the universities.
women (LFB). All three coefficients are positive and sta-
They were contacted about 12 months later via a written
tistically significantly related to wages. We also tested two
questionnaire. A total of 8,151 graduates returned the ques-
cross-level effects between GDP growth and placements
tionnaire, constituting a response rate of 65 per cent.5
via strong and weak ties. Both interaction effects are not
The data have some advantages that make them par-
significantly related to wages. Overall, the ISSP 2001 data
ticularly suitable for an analysis of our propositions. SOCIAL NETWORKS AND LABOUR MARKET OUTCOMES
Since all respondents are labour market entrances, they are
The results we present here concern the sample that
at the start of their career, and the sample is homogeneous
entered the labour market in the second half of 2000
with respect to their working biography. Many other
(which was a prosperous economic year in Switzerland).
investigations into the effects of network contacts on job
However, we also analysed the interviews from 1995, 1997,
characteristics, such as our own of the ISSP, use cross-
and 1999 of graduates entering the labour market during
sectional data from the entire working population and
more recessive periods. We did not find substantial differ-
have to control for career-specific effects, such as the last
ences, which suggests that our results do not seem to
position before the present job was entered, the segment
depend on the specific economic situation in 2000.
of the labour market, the level of on-the-job training,
The survey contains information on respondents’
whether respondents changed employer, and so forth.
search strategies, search costs, labour market outcome,
Such heterogeneity of individual working biographies
and educational adequacy. Each of these variables is
makes it more difficult to isolate the effect of network
measured by several indicators. The labour market out-
contacts on the job in question. Also, Granovetter (1995:
come is measured by wages and additionally by the occu-
154) discusses that past positions may have been found
pational position (with managing responsibilities as
by network contacts but not necessarily the present one.
opposed to without). Search costs are measured by the
However, since the past position influences the charac-
search time, the number of job applications, and the
teristics of the present job, networks can have an indirect
number of job interviews, and by a subjective measure of
effect on present positions. This indirect effect of net-
how difficult respondents perceived the job search to
works is usually not taken into account so that the net-
have been. Educational adequacy is measured by four
indicators, most importantly by the specificity of the
Another advantage of our data is that the survey took
degree that the employer required. Additionally, the
place 12 months or less (the median is 3 months) after
questionnaire contains a few subjective measures, that is,
respondents entered the labour market. Hence, biases
whether respondents believe that the job is a long-term
due to memory problems that are usually present in ret-
engagement, which offers career perspectives, the extent
rospective questioning should be less of a problem in
to which respondents can use their ability, how they per-
this data. Information about job searching can be inac-
ceive the possibility to exert influence, and how well the
curate in representative surveys that contain a cross-
wages correspond to their qualifications. Hence, the data
section of the entire labour force for those respondents
allow for an analysis of the effects of search strategies on
who have not experienced a job shift for a longer time
the labour market outcome, the search costs, and the
A further difficulty of analysing the effects of social
For the analysis of wages, we restrict the analysis to
capital is the dependence of the labour market on eco-
those graduates who received their first university degree
nomic cycles. Granovetter (1995) supposes that strong
in 2000 and had entered the labour market by the time
ties are more important during economic recessions
of the interview.6 The questionnaire distinguishes 12 dif-
than weak ties because strong ties feel more obliged to
ferent job-search strategies: for example, graduates may
help their friends or relatives in difficult times. Another
have applied directly, asked different employment agencies
possibility mentioned in Granovetter (1995) is that
(official employment office or one from the university),
employers have more bargaining power during economic
responded to job advertisements in the media, or placed
recessions than workers and may determine the job
an advertisement themselves. Graduates may also have
match weakening the influence of networks. Theories of
contacted friends, relatives, or colleagues or have looked
labour market segmentation suggest that ‘social closure’
for jobs by asking professors and former employers they
is stronger during recessive cycles, which would increase
the importance of personal contacts (Preisendörfer and
In 2001, 25.2 per cent of the graduates reported that
Voss, 1988). Some evidence of the dependence between
they received a job offer without prior search. The most
the economic situation and the shape of the labour mar-
common job-search strategy among the graduates in
ket was presented by Osberg (1993) with Canadian data.
Switzerland is direct application (50.2 per cent) followed
He found that more unemployed used social networks
by formal search strategies (46.9 per cent) and the help
during times of higher unemployment. However, at the
of personal networks (40.5 per cent).7 More important
same time, the proportion who found a job through the
than the question which strategies were employed is the
network decreased, possibly because a larger proportion
question which ones were successful. Figure 2 shows that
about a quarter of the graduates found a job through
FRANZEN AND HANGARTNER
Notice: The question wording was: „Which of the strategies you used was decisive in finding the job?“.
Figure 2 Proportion of successful search strategies, 1995–2001.
each of the search channels, that is, formal, informal,
business administration or economics are higher than
and direct applications. Moreover, these proportions
the ones from social sciences, history, or language. Fur-
remain fairly constant over time. Comparing 1995 with
thermore, the highest wages are observed among gradu-
1999, the importance of social contacts decreased a little.
ates from universities in the German-speaking part as
However, in 2001, the search via social networks was the
compared with the French and Italian part, which
decisive route into the labour market for 19.6 per cent of
depends on the shape of the regional labour markets and
the graduates. Calculating the success ratio by dividing
has little to do with the quality of the universities.8
the number of individuals who found a job by the
First of all, the results reveal that searching is
number who used a given strategy reveals no substantial
rewarded. Respondents who searched for a job receive a
differences (direct application 44.8 per cent, formal
4 per cent wage bonus as compared with those who
search 49.5 per cent, and social contacts 45.3 per cent).
accepted an offer by an employer without prior search
Summarizing the first part of our descriptive analysis
(see Table 3, model 1). However, wages do not increase
again confirms Granovetter’s (1974, 1995) first hypothe-
with increasing search time. This finding is not consist-
sis. A substantial proportion of individuals find their
ent with job-search theory, which assumes that individ-
jobs due to the help of their personal networks. This res-
uals with a higher reservation wage should search longer
ult replicates that of studies conducted in the United
and realize a higher wage. However, job-search theory
States (Young, 1974; Sagen et al., 1999).
makes the (highly unrealistic) assumption that job
The interesting question is whether job matches through
searchers know the offer distribution (see Mortensen,
social networks are beneficial as compared with other
1986). The zero effect could be the result of the mixture
strategies. Table 3 shows the results of an OLS regression
of two types of individuals in our sample: those who
of the logarithm of the hourly wages. Presented are the
search and find the better-paid jobs and those whose
effects of different search strategies controlling for other
reservation wage is higher than what the market is will-
mostly socio-demographic influences such as respond-
ing to offer and who, therefore, have difficulties finding
ents’ age, sex, or nationality. The analysis also controls for
a job that meets their reservation wage. More important
the effects of different universities and subjects of study.
with respect to our hypothesis is the negative effect on
However, we do not show the latter effects to keep the
wages if the job was found with the help of social net-
table readable. As is usual, wages for subjects such as
works. Jobs that were found through social contacts pay
SOCIAL NETWORKS AND LABOUR MARKET OUTCOMES Table 3 The influence of social networks on hourly wages, occupational position, and educational adequacy Income regression Managing position Educational adequacy *Significant at the 5% level; **significant at the 1% level. Depicted in model 1 are the unstandardized coefficients from OLS regression. Numbers in parenthesis denote the standard errors of the estimates. Model 1 is an OLS regression with the logarithm of hourly wages as the dependent variable. The model controls for university dummies and for subject dum-mies, which are not displayed due to place restrictions. The university dummies consist of Basel, Berne, Fribourg, Geneva, Lausanne, Neuchâtel, St. Gallen, Ticino, ETH Zurich, EPF Lausanne with the University of Zurich as the reference. Subjects are distinguished into Theology, Language, History, Social Sciences, Law, Natural Science, Medicine, and technical subjects. Economics is used as the reference category. Model 2 is a logistic regression. The dependent variable is coded as 1, if graduates received a job with management responsibilities, and 0 otherwise. Model 3 is an ordered-probit model. The dependent variable is the educational adequacy coded as 1 if employer did not require any university degree, 2 with only a general university degree, 3 if a university degree from similar subjects were also accepted, and 4 if the employer required a specific degree.
on average 5 per cent less as compared with jobs found
jobs for which the employer demands a specific degree
through formal search channels. Thus, also our results
as compared with more general university degrees are on
show that searching via social contacts has no monetary
average paid 5 per cent less. The results also show that
advantage (Mouw, 2003) and, moreover, might even
women have a 4 per cent wage disadvantage in the
have negative effects (see De Graaf and Flap, 1988; Flap
labour market.10 Children increase the wage by 7 per
cent, which can be explained with social benefit pay-
Also, the number of different strategies people use to
ments employers have to make. A small positive effect of
find a job does not affect wages. This finding is also
2 per cent can also be observed for the graduates’ age
inconsistent with job-search theory. A more intensive
and a 3 per cent income advantage for work experience
search should increase the number of job offers, which
acquired during university enrolment. The education of
in turn should increase the chance of finding a better-
a respondent’s father or mother does not affect a gradu-
paid job. However, this again might be due to the mix-
ate’s wage level at labour market entrance. Hourly wages
ture of two groups of individuals, namely, those who
are also not affected if respondents work only part-time
find well-paid jobs by searching and those whose
chances are worse to begin with and who are therefore
In addition to wages, we also analysed the occupa-
tional position at which graduates entered the labour
In addition to the effects of search strategies, model 1
market. The questionnaire contains a dichotomous variable
also controls for educational adequacy and certain
that indicates whether individuals received a position
socio-demographic effects. First, as hypothesized, job
with or without management responsibilities. Assuming
adequacy is negatively correlated with wages. Hence,
that management positions have more occupational
FRANZEN AND HANGARTNER
prestige, it is expected that offers from the network
0.05 and 0.10 significance level), indicating that jobs
should lead to management positions more often. Since
found via the network are perceived to offer more
we deal with a dichotomous variable, model 2 in Table 3
opportunities for personal influence and ability.12
shows the logistic-regression coefficients. However, only
Network jobs, however, are negatively associated with
direct applications lead to jobs that start in a managing
the perceived adequacy of payment (model 4 in Table 4).
position significantly less often. Apart from this, two
Thus, this finding corresponds rather well to the com-
further significant effects emerge from the model: man-
paratively lower hourly wages reported in Table 3. Also,
aging positions are more often obtained by older gradu-
noteworthy are the positive effects of the work experi-
ates and less often open for part-time employment.
ence graduates acquired during their study. Graduates
Thus, model 2 in Table 3 echoes the results obtained for
who worked while still enrolled at the university have a
better chance of finding a job that is related to their sub-
Finally, in model 3 in Table 3, we attend to the ques-
ject of study. Obviously, this work experience also
tion whether network contacts increase the probability
increases graduates’ knowledge of where to find ade-
of receiving a job with higher educational adequacy.
Graduates were asked whether their current employer
Finally, we will take a look at the search costs. If
required no university degree at all, only a general degree,
Granovetter’s (1974, 1995) and our models are correct,
one from a related subject, or a specific university degree.
graduates who use networks for job searching should
We assume that jobs that do not require a university
receive job offers more often and sooner. Thus, the
degree or only an unspecific one are less adequate for
search time should be reduced for all those who use their
graduates and less preferred by them. Since the depend-
networks. This hypothesis is supported by our analysis
ent variable has four categories that can be ordered,
of the search time. We analysed the search time until
model 3 in Table 3 presents the results of an ordered-
respondents found a job by event-history analysis (more
probit model. The results suggest that search strategies
particularly we use a Weibull model), which takes right-
matter. Respondents who searched (coefficient of 0.16),
censored cases (respondents who were still looking for a
received a job through social networks (coefficient of
job at the time of the interview) into account. Model 1 in
0.20), or applied directly (coefficient of 0.14) report to
Table 5 shows the effects on the hazard rate of leaving
have jobs that more often required an adequate degree
the stage of search and entering employment. Thus,
as compared with respondents who found jobs through
graduates using the network have an increased hazard
formal search channels.11 This result confirms our
rate of 17 per cent ((exp(0.16)–1) × 100) as opposed to
hypothesis that friends, relatives, and colleagues seem to
those who use formal job-search strategies. Moreover,
pay attention to a graduate’s educational qualifications
we analysed two more indicators of the search costs,
when informing about job opportunities.
namely, the number of applications and the number of
The adequacy of jobs that were found through social
job interviews individuals went through before accept-
networks is also better in the respondents’ own percep-
ing a job. Since these variables are count data, we analyse
tion. The participants of the survey were asked whether
them using negative-binomial models (see Cameron and
they view their current job as a temporary means to earn
Trivedi, 1998).13 The estimation results suggest that
money or as a long-term career investment, as well as
graduates who used the network wrote 11 per cent fewer
how well they are able to exert influence and apply their
applications and went through 11 per cent fewer job
abilities on the job. Clearly, jobs that are more adequate
interviews. Thus, models 2 and 3 confirm the results we
to individuals’ interest and education should be viewed
obtained through our analysis of the search time.
more often as long-term investments and should offer
Our fourth model (in Table 5) contains the analysis of
better opportunities for personal influence and ability.
respondents’ perception whether they encountered diffi-
The results of the analysis are displayed in Table 4. The
culty during the job search. This indicator also reflects
logistic regression (model 1 in Table 4) shows that grad-
the results we already obtained from models 1 through 3
uates who found their job through the network (as well
of Table 5. Respondents who used the network have a
as direct applicants) have a higher chance of finding jobs
lower chance (the odds are reduced by 0.66) to report
with a long-term career perspective (the odds increase
difficulties. Models 1 through 4 in Table 5 also control
by exp(0.43) = 1.54). Models 2 and 3 contain the results
for a number of socio-demographic effects that are pos-
of exerting influence and using their abilities at the work
sibly associated with the search costs. A few systematic
place. In both models, the non-standardized OLS-regression
and crucial results emerge from the control variables. Thus,
coefficients are significantly positive (0.17 and 0.07 on a
women and academics who are looking for part-time
SOCIAL NETWORKS AND LABOUR MARKET OUTCOMES Table 4 Social networks and subjective indicators of job adequacy Career investment Apply ability Exert influence Perceived payment †Significant at the 10% level; *significant at the 5% level; **significant at the 1% level. Numbers in parenthesis denote the standard errors. The regressions contain but do not show dummies for universities and dummies for the subject of study. Model 1 is a logistic regression. The dependent variable is coded with 1 = long-term employment intention with possibility of upward mobility and 0 = short-term employment with no upward mobility. Model 2 is an OLS regression. The dependent variable measures respondents’ rating of the adequacy of job concerning the possibility of using their knowledge and ability. Model 3 is an OLS regression. The dependent variable is the perceived adequacy concerning the possibility of having an impact on the job. Model 4 is an OLS regression; the dependent variable contains the rating of the perceived adequacy of payment. Same results were obtained for models 2 through 4 if an ordered-probit was applied instead of an OLS regression.
employment seem to encounter higher search costs. Obvi-
which may at first seem counter-intuitive, might stem
ously, the number of search strategies respondents used
from the fact that those who accepted an offer through
increases the number of applications and job interviews.
network contacts could have overall received less offersor, alternatively, had a shorter search time, which conse-quentially results in a lower realized wage. Summary and Discussion
Furthermore, we extended Montgomery’s (1992)
model by assuming that the distribution of job offers
This article tries to demonstrate that social networks
from networks is superior to the distribution of job
matter for finding a job. First, we test some implications
offers due to formal channels with respect to educational
of Granovetter’s (1974, 1995) and Montgomery’s (1992)
adequacy. We tested our hypotheses by using the Swiss
hypotheses by analysing the ISSP 2001 data. Three basic
Graduate Survey. Overall, four results emerge from this
findings emerge from this analysis. First, a substantial
analysis: First, also in this survey, a substantial propor-
proportion of individuals report that they found their
tion of individuals report that they found their first job
job through network contacts. Second, individuals with
by network contacts. Second, we analysed the hourly
a larger number of friends (particularly friends at the
wages and were not able to discover a wage bonus for
work place) indeed report to have a higher income. The
individuals who had accepted an offer through the net-
effect can be explained by Montgomery’s (1992)
work. More specifically, controlling for the search time
assumption that a larger network increases respondents’
those who accepted an offer through the network had
reservation wage and consequentially their income.
even a monetary disadvantage. Thus, our analysis con-
Third, however, jobs that are directly found with the
firms other findings (De Graaf and Flap, 1988; Flap and
help of a network tie are not better paid. This result,
FRANZEN AND HANGARTNER Table 5 Search strategies and the cost of job search Duration of Number of Number of job Difficulties in applications interviews job search †Significant at the 10% level; *significant at the 5% level; **significant at the 1% level. Numbers in brackets denote the standard errors. The regressions contain but do not show dummies for universities and dummies for the subject of study. Model 1 is a Weibull model of the hazard rate to enter employment. Models 2 and 3 are negative-binomial models with the number of applications and the number of job interviews as dependent variables. Model 4 is a logistic regression analysis, the dependent variable indicating whether respondents report difficulties in finding a job.
Third, our results suggest that jobs found with the
entrances. Other results suggest that the influence of net-
help of friends, colleagues, or relatives have a higher
works should decrease, since during recessions a larger
educational adequacy. Thus, employers more often
proportion of an individual’s network should be unem-
require a specific university degree for jobs that are
ployed as well. In order to exclude the possibility that
found by network contacts. Moreover, respondents
our results depend on the good health of the economy in
more often view jobs found over the network as long-
2000, we also analysed the data of graduates who entered
term engagements compatible with their career plans
the job market during recessive times in 1995, 1997, and
versus short-term employment that has little or no rela-
1999. However, we obtained almost identical results
tion to career plans. The notion that educational job
from the other three data sets as well.
adequacy is higher is also supported by respondents’
To summarize, the acceptance of a job offer through
evaluation of job characteristics. Thus, network jobs are
the network seems to have non-monetary advantages for
more often perceived as offering the opportunity to
labour market entrances. The help of the network
increases the chance of an appropriate match concern-
Fourth, the analyses show that searching via the net-
ing respondents’ education and the type of work. At the
work saves search costs. Hence, respondents who found
same time, our results replicate that finding a job
their job through the network did so faster, applied less
through the network has no monetary benefit. Thus, the
often, and went through a lower number of job inter-
results support Montgomery’s (1992) model as well as
views. Therefore, searching via the network has some
our extension of it that the distribution of job offers
monetary benefits regarding individual’s lifetime earn-
from the network is stochastically dominant with respect
ings. However, these benefits are small (on average
to educational adequacy. Our results also suggest that
search time is about two weeks shorter) given an indi-
graduates face a trade-off between adequacy and wages.
Higher adequacy is associated with lower entrance
As discussed above, labour market outcomes may
wages. Employers who look for specific university
depend on the business cycle. Some research suggests
degrees seem to provide general on-the-job training
that networks become more important during reces-
more often, which is associated with a steeper wage–age
sions since the market is more closed towards new
SOCIAL NETWORKS AND LABOUR MARKET OUTCOMES
Both of our data sources have particular advantages
5. The data are available from the Swiss Statistical
but also some disadvantages. Thus, our analysis of the
Graduate Survey does not allow for a test of the weak-tie
versus strong-tie hypothesis. The Graduate Survey has
6. This excludes graduates who received a second
no information concerning what type of contacts are best
degree (e.g. a dissertation) and those 4.1 per cent
with respect to finding adequate jobs. Furthermore, it
graduates who were still looking for a job at the time
contains no information on the size or other features of
individuals’ networks. We can also not exclude the pos-
7. These proportions correspond closely to those
sibility that individuals using the network for their job
reported by Young (1974), which are based on a sur-
search have some unobserved characteristics that deter-
vey of 750,000 university graduates in the United
mine the outcome of the search instead of the used
States. For a similar result concerning direct applica-
search strategy. However, the data at hand do not support
this possibility. Thus, none of the graduates reported to
8. The detailed results of universities and subjects’
have only used a single strategy, and estimating one’s
hourly wages can be obtained from the authors.
chance to use the network was only significantly related
9. Note that the estimated effect of the use of social
to the number of strategies used, as well as to gender
networks on wage might be biased if those who
(men use networks more often than women). However,
found their jobs via social networks are different in
overall the McFadden R2 of a probit model was too low
some characteristics not controlled for in the regres-
(0.04) to corroborate the obtained estimate into a treat-
sion equation from individuals who did not use
ment-effect model (Greene, 2000: 933). Thus, clarification
social contacts. One possible procedure to correct
of the problem of possible unobserved heterogeneity as
for this possible bias is the estimation of a switchingregression model (Wooldridge, 2002). However, in
well as the question to which extent the results can be
our case, the estimation of the selection equation
generalized to a larger proportion of the labour market
(probit model) did not show any fundamental dif-
has to be left to further research. However, we believe that
ferences between the two groups. The detailed
the analyses presented here draw attention to the non-
results can be obtained from the authors.
monetary benefit of social networks on the labour market. 10. If women have a lower labour market participation
than men, the analysis needs a correction (Heckit
corrections; Heckman, 1979) to obtain an unbiasedestimator. However, female participation in our
1. Most of the people interviewed did have a university
sample is about 90 per cent, so that such a correction
2. Note that Mouw (2003) calls this ‘spurious social 11. The calculation of the exact change in probabilities
capital’. This term implies that it cannot be inter-
would require further transformations of the coeffi-
preted causally. However, the argument via the res-
ervation wage implies a causal explanation. It does
12. The extent to which respondents believe that they
not need to be either the one or the other but may
can apply their ability or exert influence on the job
well be a mixture of a spurious relation and a causal
was measured on a four-point-rating scale varying
effect via wage expectations. Networks could also
from very much to not at all. Our OLS regression
increase the reservation wage by increasing the value
assumes interval measurement. However, the results
remain robust even if we apply ordered-probit mod-
3. The data are available from the Swiss Information
and Data Archive Services for the Social Sciences
13. Usually count data require the analysis via Poisson
regressions. In our case, the so-called assumption of
4. Switzerland has 12 universities, 6 in the German-
equidispersion is not fulfilled so that we apply the
speaking part (Universities of Basel, Berne, St. Gallen,
negative-binomial model. The assumption of equid-
Lucerne, Zurich, and the Swiss Federal Institute of
ispersion is fulfilled if a = Var(y|x)/E(y|x) does not
Technology in Zurich), 5 in the French-speaking
significantly deviate from 1. In model 2 a = 1.5 and
part (Universities of Fribourg, Geneva, Lausanne,
in model 3 a = 1.2 indicating over-dispersion.
Neuchâtel, and the Swiss Federal Institute of Tech-
However, the estimation results do not differ sub-
nology in Lausanne), and 1 in the Italian-speaking
stantially between the Poisson model and the
FRANZEN AND HANGARTNER Acknowledgements
Lin, N. (1999). Social Networks and Status Attainment. Annual Review of Sociology, 25, 467–487.
We are indebted to Norman Braun, Cedric El-Idrissi,
Lin, N., Vaughn, J. C. and Ensel, W. M. (1981). Social
Josef Hartmann, and Peter Preisendörfer for their help-
Resources and Occupational Status Attainment. Social Forces, 59, 1163–1181.
Lippman, S. and McCall, J. (1976). The Economics of
Job Search: A Survey. Economic Inquiry, 14, 155–189, 347–368. References
Marsden, P. and Campbell, K. (1990). Recruitment and
Selection Processes: The Organization Side of Job
Acemoglu, D. and Pischke, J. S. (1999). The Structure of
Searches. In Breiger, R. (Ed.), Social Mobility and
Wages and Investment in General Training. JournalSocial Structure. New York: Cambridge University
of Political Economy, 107, 539–572.
Becker, G. S. (1964). Human Capital. A Theoretical and
Marsden, P. and Hurlbert, J. (1988). Social Resources
Empirical Analysis with Special Reference to Educa-
and Mobility Outcomes: A Replication and Exten-
tion. New York: Columbia University Press.
sion. Social Forces, 66, 1038–1059.
Bridges, W. P. and Villemez, W. J. (1986). Informal
Mau, W.-Ch. and Kopischke, A. (2001). Job Search Meth-
Hiring and Income in the Labor Market. American
ods, Job Search Outcomes, and Job Satisfaction of Col-
Sociological Review, 51, 574–582.
lege Graduates: A Comparison of Race and Sex. Journal
Cameron, C. A. and Trivedi, P. K. (1998). Regressionof Employment Counselling, 38, 141–149. Analysis of Count Data. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge
Montgomery, J. D. (1992). Job Search and Network Com-
position: Implications of the Strength-of Weak-Ties
Corcoran, M., Datcher, L. and Duncan, G. (1980). Infor-
Hypothesis. American Sociological Review, 57, 586–596.
mation and Influence Networks in Labor Markets.
Mortensen, D. T. (1986). Job Search and Labor Market
In Duncan, G. J. and Morgan, J. N. (Eds), Five Thou-
Analysis. In Ashenfelter, O. and Layard, R. (Eds),
sand American Families: Patterns of EconomicHandbook of Labor Economics. New York: Elsevier
Progress. Ann Arbor, MI: Institute for Social
Mouw, T. (2003). Social Capital and Finding a Job: Do Con-
Coverdill, J. (1994). Personal Contacts and Post-Hire Job
tacts Matter? American Sociological Review, 68, 868–898. Outcomes. Manuscript, Department of Sociology,
Osberg, L. (1993). Fishing in Different Pools: Job-Search
and Job-finding Success in Canada in the Early
De Graaf, N. and Flap, H. (1988). With a Little Help
1980s. Journal of Labor Economics, 11, 348–386.
from My Friends: Social Resources as an Explana-
Ports, M. (1993). Trends in Job Search Methods, 1970–92.
tion of Occupational Status and Income in West
Monthly Labor Review, 116, 63–37.
Germany, The Netherlands, and the United States.
Preisendörfer, P. and Voss, Th. (1988). Arbeitsmarkt
Social Forces, 67, 452–472.
und soziale Netzwerke. Die Bedeutung sozialer Kon-
Flap, H. and Boxmann, E. (2001). Getting Started: The
takte beim Zugang zu Arbeitsplätzen. Soziale Welt,
Influence of Social Capital on the Start of
39, 104–119.
the Occupational Career. In Lin, N., Cook, K. S. and
Sagen, B., Dallam, J. and Laverty, J. (1999). Job Search
Burt, R. S. (Eds), Social Capital: Theory and Research.
Techniques as Employment Channels: Differential
New York: Aldine de Gruyter, pp. 159–181.
Effects on the Initial Employment Success of College
Granovetter, M. (1973). The Strength of Weak Ties.
Graduates. The Career Development Quarterly, 84, American Journal of Sociology, 78, 1360–1380.
Granovetter, M. (1974). Getting a Job: A Study of Con-
Staiger, D. (1990). The Effect of Connections on the Wagestacts and Careers. Chicago and London: University
and Mobility of Young Workers. Cambridge, MA:
Granovetter, M. (1995). Getting a Job: A Study of Con-
U.S. Department of Labor. (1975). Job Seeking Methods
tacts and Careers, 2nd edn. Chicago and London:
Used by American Workers. Bureau of Labor Statis-
Greene, W. H. (2000). Econometric Analysis, 4th edn.
Wegener, B. (1991). Job Mobility and Social Ties: Social
London: Prentice Hall International.
Resources, Prior Job, and Status Attainment. Ameri-
Heckman, J. (1979). Sample Selection Bias as a Specifi-
can Sociological Review, 56, 60–71.
cation Error. Econometrica, 71, 153–167.
Wooldridge, J. M. (2002). Econometric Analysis of Cross
Jann, B. (2003). Old Boy Network. Militärdienst und
Section and Panel Data. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
ziviler Berufserfolg in der Schweiz. Zeitschrift für
Young, A. (1974). Labor Market Experience of Recent
Soziologie, 32, 139–155.
College Graduates. Monthly Labor Review, 97, 33–40. SOCIAL NETWORKS AND LABOUR MARKET OUTCOMES Authors’ Addresses
Dominik Hangartner, Institute of Sociology, Univer-
sity of Bern, Lerchenweg 36, CH-3012 Bern,
Axel Franzen (to whom correspondence should be
addressed), Institute of Sociology, RWTH Aachen,Eilfschornsteinstr. 7, D-52062 Aachen, Germany. Emai
Appendix 1 Table A1 Measurement of variables, means, and proportions of the Swiss Graduate Survey
Swiss Institute of Technology in Lausanne
Adequacy of university degree concerning job
FRANZEN AND HANGARTNER Table A1 (continued)
Perception of difficulties during the search
The category History also includes Philosophy, Archaeology, History of Art, Ethnology, Music, Theatre, and Film. Social Sci-ences include Psychology, Pedagogic, Sociology, Social Work, Political Science, and Media Science. Other subjects include Ecol-ogy, Sport, and Military Science. Natural Sciences include Mathematics, Astronomy, Physics, Computer Science, Geography, Chemistry, and Biology. Economics also includes Business Administration.
2010 Frontiers in Reproduction Symposium Schedule Friday, June 11 Session I: Leslie Heckert, moderator Mike McClure Pioneer Lecture: Dr. David Page, Choosing Sex: How Germ Cells Take the Road Less Traveled Translational regulation of gene expression during oocyte and early embryo development: Role of embryonic poly(A) binding protein (ePAB) Scott Purcell '10, Washington University
WACV 2012 Organizing Committee General Chairs Terry Boult, Univ. Colorado at Colorado Springs Walter Scheirer, Univ. Colorado at Colorado Springs Program Chairs Michael Brown, National University of Singapore Ram Nevatia, University of Southern California Luc Vincent, Google Publications Chair Anderson Rocha, UNICAMP Registration Chair Ginger Boult Program C