doi: 10.1377/hlthaff.2009.0721HEALTH AFFAIRS 29,NO. 3 (2010): 364–3712010 Project HOPE—
The People-to-People HealthFoundation, Inc.
ABSTRACT In the past few decades, obesity rates among American children
.edu) is an associate professorin the Department of Policy
have skyrocketed. Although many factors have played a part in this
Analysis and Management atCornell University in Ithaca,
unhealthy increase, this paper focuses on how economic policies may be
contributing to our children’s growing girth and how these policiesmight be altered to reverse this trend. It examines the economic causesand consequences of obesity, the rationales for government intervention,the cost-effectiveness of various policies, and the need for more researchfunding.
Inthetwenty-fiveyearsthatelapsedbe- discussingtheimplicationsforhealthpolicy.
Economic explanations for the recent rise in
obesity tend to focus on changes that give people
incentives to consume more or to burn fewer
calories. These include the following.
4 percent to 15.3 percent among six-to-eleven-
FOOD PRICES The real price of food (the price of
year-olds; and from 6.1 percent to 15.5 percent
food adjusted for inflation across all goods and
services) has declined greatly in recent decades. For example, between 1990 and 2007 the realprice of a two-liter bottle of Coca-Cola fell34.89 percent, and that of a McDonald’s quar-ter-pounder with cheese fell 5.44 percent.3 Some
research indicates that reductions in the price of
food account for 41–43 percent of the rise in
Childhood obesity is a complex, multidiscipli-
young adults’ body mass index (BMI) between
nary issue, so the search for solutions requires
information sharing across many fields. To pro-
BMI is most sensitive to the price of fast food in
mote such exchange, this paper describes re-
particular for youth from families of low socio-
search findings from the field of economics.
economic status.5 The real price of fruit and veg-
Relative to other disciplines, economics has only
etables rose 17 percent between 1997 and 2003,6
recently been applied to the study of obesity. As a
an increase that some studies have linked to
result, there are many useful applications yet to
Economics offers several useful tools for the
AGRICULTURAL POLICIES The decline in the price
study of childhood obesity: insights into the eco-
of food could be due to agriculture policies. How-
nomic causes and consequences of obesity,
ever, several studies have concluded that such
clearly defined rationales for government inter-
policies have little impact on consumer prices of
vention in markets, and the use of cost-effective-
energy-dense foods.9,10 About half of farm subsi-
ness analysis for comparing policies to prevent
dies are based on historic, not current, produc-
or reduce obesity. This paper summarizes recent
tion, which limits incentives for farmers to in-
research in each of those areas. It concludes by
crease output.9 Moreover, U.S. farm policy raises
the prices of sugar (by restricting imports) and
milk (through regional dairy compacts).
In addition, the impact of farm policy on many
that the poor are more likely to be obese, the
retail food prices is modest because the cost of
extensive literature on socioeconomic status
farm products (ingredients) represents a small
and obesity includes widely varying findings.18
proportion of the food’s retail price. For exam-
For example, one recent study finds that the cor-
ple, the cost of corn—the key ingredient in high-
relation between childhood obesity and the
fructose corn syrup—contributes just 1.6 percent
income of the household varies considerably
to the price of soft drinks.11 It is estimated that
by race, sex, age, and year. The study also found
agriculture subsidies, by decreasing the prices of
a negative correlation between childhood obe-
food, raise the BMI of youth by 0.08 percent, or a
Subsidizing the production of corn and re-
may contribute to childhood obesity. It is esti-
stricting imports of sugar have given food man-
mated that the increase in a mother’s average
ufacturers, particularly the producers of soft
weekly work hours explains 11.8–34.6 percent
drinks, an incentive to substitute high-fructose
of the rise in childhood obesity in high-socio-
corn syrup for sugar.11 Some researchers have
economic-status families between 1975 and
argued that this shift contributes to increased
1994.20 A subsequent study found an association
food intake and obesity because fructose, unlike
between maternal employment and childhood
the glucose in sugar, does not stimulate insulin
obesity only for children whose mothers were
secretion or leptin production, both of which
employed full time when the child was seven
regulate food intake.13 However, the link be-
years old. This association was not found for
tween high-fructose corn syrup and obesity
children whose mothers worked full time when
the child was either preschool age or age eleven,
Another way in which agriculture policy con-
or for children whose mothers worked part time
tributes to increased food consumption and thus
obesity is that the U.S. government requires pro-
ducers of agricultural commodities that enjoy
television than children whose mothers do not
price supports to contribute a specific amount
work outside the home.22 In addition, working
of money for each unit they sell into a fund that is
mothers spend less time cooking and eating with
used for commodity-specific advertising and re-
their children than mothers who do not work
search. Among other things, these funds are
outside the home, which increases the probabil-
used to support the advertising of fast-food
ity that the family will consume prepared foods.
menu items, which in turn raises the risk of
These decreases in time spent cooking and eat-
ing with children are only slightly offset by
INCOME Income is another potential contribu-
increases in time spent at such activities by hus-
tor to obesity. Higher income could prevent
weight gain by enabling consumers to substitute
Child care arrangements for the offspring of
healthier, more costly food for cheaper energy-
working mothers have also been correlated with
dense food or by increasing demand for good
an increased risk of childhood obesity. Children
health or an attractive appearance.15 On the
in center-based care are more likely to be obese
other hand, additional income could promote
than children cared for by nonparental relatives
weight gain by allowing people to consume more
or by a nanny.24 This may be attributable to differ-
calories and spend more time in sedentary pur-
ences across the environments in the quality of
suits. These conflicting effects may explain why
research so far has found little or no evidence
ing alcoholic beverages, but research has notborne that out. Studies find only about a 10 per-
cent correlation among these behaviors.28
obesity include labor-market costs to the
Economic Consequences OfChildhood Obesity
The economic consequences of childhoodobesity are typically categorized as direct, such
as medical costs, and indirect, such as job absen-teeism. The direct costs of childhood obesity in-
clude annual prescription drug, emergencyroom, and outpatient costs of $14.1 billion,29 plusinpatient costs of $237.6 million.30
An even larger cost is incurred when obese
children become obese adults. About a thirdof obese preschool children, and about half
The government could tax obesity itself (which
of obese school-age children, become obese
would presumably be politically unpopular), or
adults.31 The estimated annual cost of treating
tax the behavior that contributes to obesity and
obesity-related illness in adults is $147 billion.32
subsidize behavior that contributes to healthy
The medical costs of obesity are so substantial
that the rise in obesity explains 27 percent of the
Another government intervention that might
rise in health care spending between 1987 and
be useful is to provide consumers with more
2001.33 A limitation of this research is that
information about the food they eat. Recently,
obesity may be correlated with unobservable fac-
cities such as New York have required fast-food
tors that directly affect medical costs; for exam-
chain restaurants to list the calorie content of
ple, a person may have sustained a disabling
their food on menus and menu boards.38 It is not
injury that leads to obesity as well as raises medi-
yet clear whether such menu labeling affects
food choices and, ultimately, obesity.
The indirect costs of obesity include labor-
More is known about the effects of the Nutri-
market costs to the obese individual and poten-
tion Facts panel, which has been required on
tially the employer. Obesity is associated with
packaged foods since 1994. Since the Nutrition
delayed skill acquisition in children as young
Facts panel was introduced, Americans have in-
as two to three years old.34 Even when education
creased consumption of iron and fiber, although
and cognitive ability are controlled for, adult
they have not lowered consumption of total fat,
obesity is associated with lower wages, especially
for white females.35 In addition, obesity-related
Obesity prevalence among white females who
job absenteeism totals $4.3 billion annually.36
use the labels when shopping is 2.67 percentage
Also, obesity is associated with lower productiv-
points lower than it would have been in the ab-
ity while at work (presenteeism), which totals
sence of the labels (no significant effect of the
labels on weight was found for other demo-graphic groups).40
Another economic rationale for government
intervention in markets is to protect consumers
who are acting irrationally. This criterion should
One economic rationale for government inter-
be used cautiously, because irrationality is in the
vention is to internalize external costs, which
means to ensure that all of the costs associated
However, children arguably are not able to
with obesity are borne by those whose decisions
take into account the future consequences of
create the costs. In 2008 obesity-related illness
their actions, and children as old as age eleven
cost Medicare $19.7 billion and Medicaid, $8 bil-
may fail to appreciate the difference between
lion.32 These costs were borne by the general
television advertisements and television pro-
population, whose tax dollars fund these federal
gramming.41 As a result, some European coun-
and state health insurance programs. In addi-
tries have banned food companies from adver-
tion, private health insurance plans paid $49 bil-
tising to children.41 It is estimated that a ban on
lion to treat obesity-related illness in 2008.32
television fast-food advertising to children in the
Some of this cost also was borne by the nonobese
United States would reduce the prevalence of
in the form of higher group health insurance
overweight by 18 percent among children ages
3–11 and by 14 percent among youths ages 12–
18.42 However, it is difficult to accurately mea-
cure” is true in this case. Treating adult obesity
sure the effect of food ads on weight because
with the drug orlistat costs $8,327 per QALY,46
exposure to the ads is correlated with sedentary
the drug sibutramine costs $9,299 per QALY.47
lifestyle and other factors that contribute to
Gastric bypass surgery costs $5,000–$16,100
per QALY for women and $10,000–$35,600 perQALY for men.48 Wheeling Walks, a behaviormodification program targeted to sedentary
adults, costs $14,286 per QALY; other behavior
To get the biggest “bang for the buck” in prevent-
modification programs for adults cost much
ing childhood obesity, decision makers can use
cost-effectiveness analysis, which compares in-
Of course, not every prevention strategy is
terventions in terms of their cost per quality-
more cost-effective than every treatment. For ex-
adjusted life-year (QALY) saved.43 Exhibit 1 lists
ample, the Moving School Bus program, which
some of the available data on the cost-effective-
encourages children to walk rather than ride to
school, is neither effective nor cost-effective.50
Based on the published literature, the most
Limitations of these cost-effectiveness analy-
cost-effective way to prevent obesity in youth
ses include many uncertainties, such as how
is the Coordinated Approach to Child Health
effectively participants maintain weight loss
(CATCH), a comprehensive intervention to pro-
mote healthy eating and physical activity inelementary schools, which costs $900 per QALYsaved.44 The next most cost-effective program is
Planet Health, a comprehensive intervention to
Public opinion polls indicate that most Ameri-
promote healthy eating and physical activity in
cans consider childhood obesity to be a major
middle schools, which costs $4,305 per QALY
public health problem.51 In a 2008 nationwide
saved for girls but is not effective for boys.45
survey, obesity was ranked as the number-one
The adage that “prevention is cheaper than
Cost Per Quality-Adjusted Life-Year (QALY) Saved Of Various Interventions To Prevent Or Reduce Obesity
walking, frequent calls to promptparticipants to walk
However, polls may be misleading indicators
of taxpayers’ “willingness to pay” higher taxesfor obesity prevention programs. So-called con-
tingent valuation survey methods, which areused to estimate the value of goods not traded
in markets, indicate that although 83 percent ofNew York State residents agree that childhood
obesity is a major problem, more than a third
refuse to pay even $10 a year in higher taxes to cutchildhood obesity in half.53 Collectively, how-
ever, society is willing to pay substantialamounts to reduce childhood obesity. The meanwillingness to pay for a 50 percent reduction inchildhood obesity in New York State was $46.41,which implies a total willingness to pay by NewYork State residents of $690.6 million.53
The level of public support for anti-obesity
these differences is statistically significant
policies is greatly influenced by how the issue
(p < 0:01). Thus, how the issue of costs is framed
of costs is framed. The 2009 Empire State Poll of
can cut support by more than half, from 92.1 per-
New York State residents asked respondents
cent to 40.5 percent, and can increase opposition
whether they agree with improving the nutrition
twelvefold, from 4.4 percent to 53.2 percent.
of food in school cafeterias (Exhibit 2) and in-
Similar patterns are shown in Exhibit 3 for
creasing the quantity and quality of physical ed-
questions about increasing the quantity and
ucation in schools (Exhibit 3). For each of these
quality of physical education in schools. Clearly,
policies, respondents were randomly asked one
there is a need for caution when using poll
of three versions of a question that varied in how
results to gauge public support for specific
explicitly costs of the policy were discussed.
policies—support may be highly sensitive to
Exhibit 2 shows that if no mention is made of
how questions are worded, especially with re-
costs, 92.1 percent agree and only 4.4 percent
disagree with improving the nutrition of food inschool cafeterias. If the question is modified toend “even if it requires raising taxes,” agreement
falls to 69.5 percent and disagreement quintu-
Inevitably, government efforts to prevent and
ples, to 22.6 percent. If the question begins with
reduce childhood obesity will have limited bud-
a discussion of costs by saying “The government
gets. To maximize the benefit to society, it is
should raise taxes in order to improve the nutri-
necessary to spend that limited budget on the
tion of food in school cafeterias,” only 40.5 per-
anti-obesity interventions that are most cost-
cent agree and 53.2 percent disagree. Each of
How The Framing Of Costs Influences Public Support For Improving The Nutrition Of School Food
The government should improve the nutrition of food in school
The government should improve the nutrition of food in school
cafeterias, even if it requires raising taxes
The government should raise taxes in order to improve the nutrition of
SOURCE Author’s calculations, using data from the 2009 Empire State Poll. NOTES The 2009 Empire State Poll (ESP) of 800 respondentswas conducted 30 January–16 March 2009. Respondents were selected using the random-digit-dial method, and the interview wasconducted using a computer-assisted telephone interviewing software system. The random sampling frame allows poll results tobe generalized to the entire state of New York. Percentages do not add to 100 because respondents also had the option ofanswering that they were “neutral,” answering “don’t know,” or refusing to answer. In the second and third rows, the portion of thequestion that is underlined indicates the part of the question that differs from the wording in the first row. It does not indicatethat the interviewer emphasized those words when asking the question. The difference in values across rows within a column isstatistically significant (p < 0:01) in each case.
How The Framing Of Costs Influences Public Support for Improving Physical Education In Schools
The government should increase the quality and quantity of physical
The government should increase the quality and quantity of physical
education in schools, even if it requires raising taxes
The government should raise taxes in order to increase the quality and
quantity of physical education in schools
SOURCE Author’s calculations, using data from the 2009 Empire State Poll. NOTES: See Exhibit 2
SET PRIORITIES For example, the school-based
provide a rationale for taxes and subsidies to
program CATCH is highly cost-effective.44 The
promote healthy eating. Experiments have es-
wide variations in cost-effectiveness shown in
tablished that altering food prices can change
Exhibit 1 underscore the importance of prioritiz-
youth behavior. Cutting the prices of fruit, salad,
ing interventions with the lowest cost per QALY,
and carrots in high school cafeterias in half re-
to avoid wasting resources. Unfortunately, cost-
sulted in a quadrupling of sales of fruit and a
effectiveness studies have not yet been con-
doubling of sales of baby carrots, although it did
ducted for many promising interventions. Re-
not significantly affect sales of salads.58 Other
search is, in many cases, at the earlier stage of
experiments with vending machines in high
determining whether the intervention is effec-
schools found that the quantity and type of
tive at all. The National Institutes of Health
snacks purchased were significantly affected by
(NIH) should continue to invest in cost-effective-
price.59 A limitation of these studies is that they
ness studies of anti-obesity interventions, to bet-
do not track consumption in all places and at all
ter inform funding decisions and ensure that the
times. Also, it remains unclear whether total
limited funds allocated to obesity prevention and
caloric intake rises or falls when low-calorie
treatment yield the maximum improvement in
A challenge for food taxes is defining the scope
of what should be taxed and what should be
mandate that private health insurance plans
subsidized. Should apple juice be taxed because
cover cost-effective methods of preventing and
it is energy-dense, or should it be subsidized
treating childhood obesity.55 These policies may
because it is 100 percent fruit and sometimes
not be covered in the absence of a mandate be-
contains added vitamins? Prominent public
cause high turnover of enrollees implies that it is
health advocates have recently called for taxes
profit-maximizing for health insurance compa-
on full-calorie soda.60 The mean published esti-
nies to refuse to reimburse for prevention and
mate is that a 1 percent increase in soda price
treatment that do not generate short-term sav-
would reduce the quantity of soda demanded by
ings. As a result, many health insurance plans do
0.79 percent.61 The modest soft drink taxes that
not reimburse doctors for preventing and treat-
currently exist appear to have negligible effect on
body weight.62 A challenge for estimating the
impact on obesity of a substantial soft drink
health insurance programs should cover cost-
tax is that no such taxes currently exist.
effective methods of prevention and treatment.
A risk of taxing a narrow set of energy-dense
West Virginia and Pennsylvania have been in-
foods (such as soda) is that consumers may “sub-
novators in addressing obesity by expanding
stitute away” from the taxed items toward
Medicaid coverage—for example, for nutrition
energy-dense items that are not taxed. Another
education.57 A handful of states are incorporat-
challenge is that food taxes can be regressive,
ing incentives for healthy behavior into their
falling more heavily on the poor. Several states
Medicaid and Children’s Health Insurance Pro-
that tax food, including Hawaii, Idaho, Kansas,
Oklahoma, South Dakota, and Wyoming, both
praised for encouraging healthy behavior and
tax food and provide an income tax credit or
criticized for placing the health of low-income
rebate to low-income households that compen-
children at risk by linking the provision of serv-
sates them for the loss of their purchasing
USE INCENTIVES The external costs of obesity
search and policy can help identify contributors
Obesity is a major public health problem facing
to obesity, calculate the consequences of obesity,
the United States, with significant consequences
and allocate scarce resources to the interven-
for health care costs and productivity. Incorpo-
tions that offer the greatest benefit per dollar
rating the economic perspective into obesity re-
Johnson Foundation’s Scholars in Health
3 Christian T, Rashad I. Trends in U.S.
tion and costs in childhood. Obesity.
hospital care and costs, 1999–2005.
payer- and service-specific estimates.
34 Cawley J, Spiess CK. Obesity and skill
policy: fact or rhetoric? Food Policy.
26 Cutler DM, Glaeser EL, Shapiro JM.
obesity. Am J Med. 2002;113:491–8.
choices. J Nutr. 2003;133:841S–3S.
(NY): Oxford University Press; 1996.
implications for taxes and subsidies.
tients with type 2 diabetes mellitus.
63 Federation of Tax Administrators.
to do with it? Health Aff (Millwood).
Responsabile UOS Anestesia e Analgesia Ostetrico-Ginecologica UOC Anestesia e Rianimazione per il Dipartimento Materno Infantile NAUSEA E IL VOMITO NEL POST-OPERATORIO La nausea e il vomito nel post-operatorio (PONV) hanno un’'incidenza che varia tra il 20% e il 30% in rapporto a fattori di pertinenza chirurgica e propri del paziente. Sebbene la profilassi routinaria sembrerebbe appropriat
Newsletter October 2012 for Health & Life Science Industry Neurim – Supplementary Protection Certificates may now be available for previously authorised active ingredients by Kilian Schärli, author of a Ph.D. (to be published) about SPC in Switzerland On July 19, 2012, the Court of Justice of the European Union ("CJEU") issued a hotly anticipated decision in the case